Citation: |
[1] |
E. Accinelli and G. Brida, The ramsey model with logistic population growth, Economics Bulletin, 3 (2007), 1-8. |
[2] |
E. Accinelli and G. Brida, Population growth and the Solow-Swan model, International Journal of Ecological Economics and Statistics, 8 (2007), 54-63. |
[3] |
A. Alonso, C. Echevarria and K. C. Tran, Long-run economic performance and the labor market, Southern Economic Journal, 79 (2004), 905-919. |
[4] |
L. Fanti and P. Manfredi, The Solow's model with endogenous population, Journal of Economic Development, 28 (2003), 103-115. |
[5] |
O. Galor, From stagnation to growth: Unified growth theory, Handbook of Economic Growth, (2005), 171-293. |
[6] |
L. Guerrini, The Solow-Swan model with a bounded population growth rate, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 42 (2006), 14-21.doi: 10.1016/j.jmateco.2005.05.001. |
[7] |
G. D. Hansen and E. C. Prescott, Malthus to solow, American Economic Review, 92 (2002), 1205-1217. |
[8] |
A. Irmen, Malthus and Solow - a note on closed-form solutions, Economics Bulletin, 10 (2004), 1-6. |
[9] |
T. R. Malthus, An Essay on the Principle of Population, J. Johnson, London, 1798. |
[10] |
R. M. Solow, A contribution to the theory of economic growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70 (1956), 65-94. |
[11] |
T. W. Swan, Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation, Economic Record, 32 (1956), 334-361. |
[12] |
N. Voigtländer and H.-J. Voth, The three horsemen of riches: Plague, war, and urbanization in early modern europe, SSRN 1029347. Revised 2011. |
[13] |
J. G. Williamson, Growth, distribution, and demography: Some lessons from history, Explorations in Economic History, 35 (1998), 241-271. |